The premiers of Ontario and Quebec are preparing to impose stricter limits on emissions of fossil fuels to combat climate change. They and others favour an approach dubbed cap and trade, which is frequently described as a market solution to pollution. But in reality, theres not much that is market friendly about cap and trade, and no amount of rhetorical masquerading can conceal the costly consequences that enactment would inflict on both provinces.
Details of the regulations have yet to be finalized, but the two Liberal premiers signed a memorandum of understanding on June 2 that calls for strong, immediate and sustained action to minimize the risks posed by climate change (Ontario, 2008). Their ultimate goal is emission reductions of carbon dioxide to 1990 levelsa slightly lower target than that of the Kyoto Protocol, but extreme nonetheless.
Given the considerable uncertainties about climate change, it can reasonably be argued that the premiers are acting with undue haste. They compound the error by touting cap and trade as a flexible, market-based mechanism.
Under a cap-and-trade program, the government sets an overall limit (cap) on emissions. Based on that cap, quotas are imposed on individual sources of emissions, such as utilities and factories. The government allocates allowances to each facility that represents the volume of their quota. A facility must either reduce emissions to meet the quota or purchase allowances from those that have exceeded their required reductions (trade).
Europe adopted cap and trade in 2005 and the results were far from stellar, according to a variety of reports. The Washington Post, for example, described it as a bureaucratic morass with a host of unexpected and costly side effects and a much smaller effect on carbon emissions than planned (Mufson, 2007, Apr. 9).
Cap and trade does sound friendlier than CO2 rationing or carbon taxes. But at its core, this regulatory regime encompasses both. It is based on the creation of a scarcity by government fiat (the cap on CO2 emissions) and the rationing of remaining supply through government-imposed quotas. The cost of compliance constitutes a tax by raising the cost of carbon-based fuels to curtail use.
The precise levels at which the overall cap and the quotas ultimately are set are wholly arbitrary. No matter what politicians or the media claim, no one knows the amount of emissions that make a difference in global temperatures. Therefore, there is no correct cap to address climate change. That leaves politicians and lobbyists for all sorts of special intereststransportation, manufacturing, utilities and agricultureto haggle over the quotas. And that makes cap and trade a political mechanism, not a market mechanism.
We are thus left to hope that regulators make a small mistake instead of a big one. For example, a low cap (requiring significant emissions reductions) would be costlier and thus create economic hardship throughout the economy. Conversely, a high cap (requiring smaller emissions reductions) would waste resources because the cost of emissions reductions would be greater than the benefitto the extent there is any benefit at all.
Big corporations are likely to weather the regulations better than small firmsespecially if the government allocates emissions allowances free of charge. The cost of emissions control technology or the purchase of additional allowances would likely be paid by consumers in the form of higher prices. But theres no additional product or service provided in return, nor are the emissions reductions likely to produce any tangible benefit. Consequently, cap and trade constitutes a massive wealth transfer from consumers to businesses. Some companies will even make a killing by brokering emissions credits. Indeed, Enron was not driven by altruism in ardently championing cap and trade.
The worst effects will likely be felt by those trying to break into the market after cap and trade is launched. Newcomers will face a competitive disadvantage before they even open their doors; having not obtained free allowances from the government, their costs will be greater than those of their competitors. Simply put, cap and trade raises barriers to entry in a most un-market-like fashion.
Proponents point to the use of cap and trade in reducing emissions of sulfur dioxide as proof of its utility. But there are significant differences between the two applications. In the case of sulfur dioxide, the technology for capturing emissions was commercially available when the cap-and-trade program was imposedunlike emissions controls for carbon dioxide. Moreover, the emissions strictures were imposed on only one sectorpower plantsunlike the CO2 limits which would encompass all segments of the economy.
Because control technologies for CO2 are nascent, the actual costs of emissions reductions are unknown and likely to fluctuate over time. This will create volatility in the price of allowances, thereby adding greater uncertainty to investment decisions. Most economists recognize that uncertainty repels rather than attracts investment.
The market is already responding to claims of climate change with hybrid cars, green power programs, voluntary emissions reductions, and the like. Government rationing of carbon-based emissions should not be confused with voluntary conservation options. The principle difference is that under cap and trade, the government would not offer citizens the choice of participation and would force us to pay the cost. Thats not how the market works.
Commentary
Costly consequences: Cap and trade is not a market-based solution
EST. READ TIME 4 MIN.Share this:
Facebook
Twitter / X
Linkedin
The premiers of Ontario and Quebec are preparing to impose stricter limits on emissions of fossil fuels to combat climate change. They and others favour an approach dubbed cap and trade, which is frequently described as a market solution to pollution. But in reality, theres not much that is market friendly about cap and trade, and no amount of rhetorical masquerading can conceal the costly consequences that enactment would inflict on both provinces.
Details of the regulations have yet to be finalized, but the two Liberal premiers signed a memorandum of understanding on June 2 that calls for strong, immediate and sustained action to minimize the risks posed by climate change (Ontario, 2008). Their ultimate goal is emission reductions of carbon dioxide to 1990 levelsa slightly lower target than that of the Kyoto Protocol, but extreme nonetheless.
Given the considerable uncertainties about climate change, it can reasonably be argued that the premiers are acting with undue haste. They compound the error by touting cap and trade as a flexible, market-based mechanism.
Under a cap-and-trade program, the government sets an overall limit (cap) on emissions. Based on that cap, quotas are imposed on individual sources of emissions, such as utilities and factories. The government allocates allowances to each facility that represents the volume of their quota. A facility must either reduce emissions to meet the quota or purchase allowances from those that have exceeded their required reductions (trade).
Europe adopted cap and trade in 2005 and the results were far from stellar, according to a variety of reports. The Washington Post, for example, described it as a bureaucratic morass with a host of unexpected and costly side effects and a much smaller effect on carbon emissions than planned (Mufson, 2007, Apr. 9).
Cap and trade does sound friendlier than CO2 rationing or carbon taxes. But at its core, this regulatory regime encompasses both. It is based on the creation of a scarcity by government fiat (the cap on CO2 emissions) and the rationing of remaining supply through government-imposed quotas. The cost of compliance constitutes a tax by raising the cost of carbon-based fuels to curtail use.
The precise levels at which the overall cap and the quotas ultimately are set are wholly arbitrary. No matter what politicians or the media claim, no one knows the amount of emissions that make a difference in global temperatures. Therefore, there is no correct cap to address climate change. That leaves politicians and lobbyists for all sorts of special intereststransportation, manufacturing, utilities and agricultureto haggle over the quotas. And that makes cap and trade a political mechanism, not a market mechanism.
We are thus left to hope that regulators make a small mistake instead of a big one. For example, a low cap (requiring significant emissions reductions) would be costlier and thus create economic hardship throughout the economy. Conversely, a high cap (requiring smaller emissions reductions) would waste resources because the cost of emissions reductions would be greater than the benefitto the extent there is any benefit at all.
Big corporations are likely to weather the regulations better than small firmsespecially if the government allocates emissions allowances free of charge. The cost of emissions control technology or the purchase of additional allowances would likely be paid by consumers in the form of higher prices. But theres no additional product or service provided in return, nor are the emissions reductions likely to produce any tangible benefit. Consequently, cap and trade constitutes a massive wealth transfer from consumers to businesses. Some companies will even make a killing by brokering emissions credits. Indeed, Enron was not driven by altruism in ardently championing cap and trade.
The worst effects will likely be felt by those trying to break into the market after cap and trade is launched. Newcomers will face a competitive disadvantage before they even open their doors; having not obtained free allowances from the government, their costs will be greater than those of their competitors. Simply put, cap and trade raises barriers to entry in a most un-market-like fashion.
Proponents point to the use of cap and trade in reducing emissions of sulfur dioxide as proof of its utility. But there are significant differences between the two applications. In the case of sulfur dioxide, the technology for capturing emissions was commercially available when the cap-and-trade program was imposedunlike emissions controls for carbon dioxide. Moreover, the emissions strictures were imposed on only one sectorpower plantsunlike the CO2 limits which would encompass all segments of the economy.
Because control technologies for CO2 are nascent, the actual costs of emissions reductions are unknown and likely to fluctuate over time. This will create volatility in the price of allowances, thereby adding greater uncertainty to investment decisions. Most economists recognize that uncertainty repels rather than attracts investment.
The market is already responding to claims of climate change with hybrid cars, green power programs, voluntary emissions reductions, and the like. Government rationing of carbon-based emissions should not be confused with voluntary conservation options. The principle difference is that under cap and trade, the government would not offer citizens the choice of participation and would force us to pay the cost. Thats not how the market works.
Share this:
Facebook
Twitter / X
Linkedin
Diane Katz
STAY UP TO DATE
More on this topic
Related Articles
By: Kenneth P. Green
By: Julio Mejía and Elmira Aliakbari
By: Jock Finlayson and Elmira Aliakbari
By: Ross McKitrick
STAY UP TO DATE