You can believe in climate science without supporting every proposed climate policy
There’s an assumption out there that if you “accept” the science of climate change you are obliged to support drastic measures to cut greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. This is not true. One does not follow from the other. Mainstream science and economics do not support much of the current climate policy agenda, and certainly not the radical extremes demanded by activist groups.
In a recent peer-reviewed paper, my co-authors and I proved this using one of the economic models governments and academics around the world rely on. Policymakers compute the social costs of GHG emissions using tools called Integrated Assessment Models (IAMs), which contains linked climate and economic models. They run the world forward in time for a few hundred years and estimate the value of damages from a tonne of GHGs emitted today. Pardon all the acronyms, but that’s called the Social Cost of Carbon or SCC, and it represents an upper bound on what we should pay, per tonne, to cut emissions.
The higher the SCC, the more aggressive climate policy should be. During the Obama years the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) convened an expert group to use IAMs to estimate the SCC from now to mid-century, to guide regulatory rule-making. Most of their results were in the US$20 to US$60 per tonne range, depending on the discount rate (which controls how much weight to put on far future damages). This means that policies shouldn’t cost more than $60 per tonne of reduction to implement.
Like all models, IAMs depend on some key parameters based on the scientific literature. It has long been known that while CO2 is a greenhouse gas, it’s also food for plants, and extra CO2 benefits plant growth. Yet two of the three IAMs assume that boosting the carbon dioxide content of the air has no effect on agriculture, which is overly pessimistic. One of the models allows for a small gain in agricultural productivity as CO2 levels rise, based on estimates of the effect from the 1990s.
Over the past decade there has been a lot of research looking at effects on global plant growth from rising CO2 levels. Results from satellite-based surveys and field experiments have shown larger benefits than people predicted in the 1990s, especially for the rice crop in Asia, even in a warmer climate, so we updated the model to incorporate this information.
Also, all the IAMs assume the climate will warm by three degrees Celsius with every CO2 doubling. This is based on simulations with large climate models, but there have been many recent studies in climate journals estimating lower sensitivity based on observed ground- and satellite-measured temperature changes. So we incorporated this information as well.
Based on these updates alone, we showed that, even using a low discount rate, the SCC (again, that’s the Social Cost of Carbon) as of 2020 drops from US$32 per tonne to about sixty cents, and there’s a 50/50 chance it’s below zero. It grows over time, but not much. By 2050 it’s still under $3 per tonne, and has a 46 per cent chance of being less than zero.
Note that we did not say “climate change is a hoax so we shouldn’t do anything.” We relied on scientific studies in mainstream journals, combined with the same model the EPA used, to determine if costly climate policies are justified. The answer is no, at least for the next few decades.
Our paper was reviewed by three knowledgeable anonymous experts who were surprised by our findings and aggressively challenged them, with one strongly recommending our study be rejected. We had to rebut their extensive counterarguments in detail. We were able to defend our calculations, and the journal decided in our favour.
If you don’t believe the science of climate change, then you obviously won’t support carbon taxes and other such policies. But it’s important to note that if you do accept the science, you aren’t obliged to support every policy, no matter how costly or inconvenient, that gets put forward. We should still focus on no-regrets strategies where the benefits outweigh the costs.