Stop the Tax Cartel

Printer-friendly version
Appeared in The National Post, October 14, 2003
Tax competition exists when people can reduce tax burdens by shifting capital and/or labor from high-tax jurisdictions to low-tax jurisdictions. This migration disciplines profligate governments and rewards nations that engage in pro-growth tax reform. This process is good for the global economy since lower tax rates increase incentives to work, save, and invest.

Not surprisingly, some high-tax governments despise tax competition and would like to see it reduced or eliminated. They have even convinced the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), an international bureaucracy representing developed nations, to launch an anti-tax competition initiative. As part of this project, the OECD created a “tax haven” blacklist, and has threatened these jurisdictions with financial protectionism unless they agree to help high-tax nations track – and tax – flight capital. The latest development is that the OECD will be hosting a Global Forum in Ottawa October 14-15, a meeting designed to pressure low-tax jurisdictions into surrendering their fiscal sovereignty.

Tax competition should be celebrated, not persecuted. It is a powerful force for economic liberalization, one that has helped promote good tax policy around the world. Indeed, even OECD economists have admitted that, “the ability to choose the location of economic activity offsets shortcomings in government budgeting processes, limiting a tendency to spend and tax excessively.” Fiscal rivalry among governments has produced an amazingly desirable impact on fiscal policy in the last 25 years. Examples abound but here are just a few:

(1) The Thatcher/Reagan tax rate reductions – Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Reagan inherited weak economies but managed to restore growth and vitality with free market reforms. Sweeping tax rate reductions were a significant component of both the Thatcher and Reagan agendas. The top tax rate was 83 percent when Thatcher took office, and she reduced the top rate to 40 percent. The top tax rate in the United States was 70 percent when Reagan was inaugurated, and he lowered it to 28 percent. Britain and the United States both benefited from tax rate reductions, but other nations also profited because they were compelled to lower their own tax rates – and this shift to better tax policy is an ongoing process. Even the OECD, which is hardly sympathetic to pro-growth tax policy, estimated that economies grow ½ of one percent faster for every 10-percentage point reduction in marginal tax rates.

(2) Corporate rate reduction in Europe – The Irish Miracle is perhaps the most impressive evidence of how tax competition advances good tax policy. Less than 20 years ago, Ireland was the “sick man of Europe” – an economic basket case with double-digit unemployment and an anemic economy. This weak performance was caused, at least in part, by an onerous tax burden. As recently as 1991, the top tax rate on personal income 52 percent, 50 percent on capital gains, and 43 percent on corporate income. Over the next 10 years, tax rates were slashed dramatically, especially on capital gains and corporate income. Today, the personal income tax rate is 42 percent, the capital gains tax rate is just 20 percent and the corporate income tax rate is only 12.5 percent. These aggressive supply-side tax rate reductions yielded enormous benefits. The Irish economy experienced the strongest growth of all industrialized nations, expanding at an average rate of 7.7 percent in the 1990s. In a remarkably short period of time, the “sick man of Europe” became the “Celtic Tiger.” Thanks to tax competition, Ireland’s tax rate reductions have had a positive effect on the rest of Europe. The Irish Miracle has motivated other EU nations to significantly reduce their tax rates in recent years, bringing the average corporate tax rate down to about 30 percent.

(3) Tax reform in Eastern Europe – One of the most amazing fiscal policy developments is the adoption of flat taxes in former Soviet Bloc nations. The three Baltic nations – Estonia, Lithuania, and Latvia – adopted flat tax systems in the 1990s. Tax reform in the Baltics triggered a virtuous cycle of tax competition. Russia followed with a 13 percent flat tax that took effect in 2001. Ukraine just approved a 13 percent flat tax, and Slovakia is implementing a 19 percent flat tax. Even Serbia has a variant of a flat tax. The evidence already shows that good tax policy is having a desirable impact. The Baltic nations, for instance, are the most prosperous of the former Soviet Union. The Russian Federation is the next most prosperous of the former Soviet Republics. The evidence from Russia is particularly striking. The Russian economy has expanded by about 10 percent since it adopted a flat tax. That may not sound like much, but it is rather noteworthy considering the slowdown in the global economy. The Russian economy certainly performed better than the United States, and easily outpaced the anemic growth rates elsewhere in Europe.

(4) Canadian tax reductions – Alberta and Ontario lead the way. Canada has not been immune to tax competition. Tax rates on personal and corporate income have generally been falling since the early-to-mid 1990s with provinces like Alberta and Ontario acting as catalyst for the rest of the country. Even more socialist-leaning provinces like Saskatchewan have reduced tax rates to remain competitive. The combination of fiscal restraint coupled with moderate tax relief ushered in a five-year period (1997 to 2001) of tremendous prosperity for the country as a whole.

Unfortunately, the tax harmonization agenda is a distinct threat to the right of nations to reform their tax codes and enact single-rate, consumption-base tax systems. The tax harmonization agenda certainly means that tax reform would be very unlikely. The flat tax, for instance, is a territorial system. Yet the OECD and other international bureaucracies believe that territorial taxation is a form of “harmful” competition. The flat tax eliminates double taxation, but the OECD initiative is designed to help governments discriminate against income that is saved and invested.

Several Nobel Prize winners have commented on tax competition. James Buchanan points out that “tax competition among separate units…is an objective to be sought in its own right.” Milton Friedman writes, “Competition among national governments in the public services they provide and in the taxes they impose is every bit as productive as competition among individuals or enterprises in the goods and services they offer for sale and the prices at which they offer them.” And Gary Becker observed that “competition among nations tends to produce a race to the top rather than to the bottom by limiting the ability of powerful and voracious groups and politicians in each nation to impose their will at the expense of the interests of the vast majority of their populations.”

Subscribe to the Fraser Institute

Get the latest news from the Fraser Institute on the latest research studies, news and events.